Sie zeigen eine alte Version dieser Seite an. Zeigen Sie die aktuelle Version an.

Unterschiede anzeigen Seitenhistorie anzeigen

« Vorherige Version anzeigen Version 4 Nächste Version anzeigen »

A. Definitions

I. General

In general, tying and bundling refer to sales strategies where firms offer a combination of distinctive products.If employed by a dominant firm, such sales strategies may be regarded abusive and prohibited under Art 102 of the TFEU. Tying and bundling have common elements and they are associated with the same competition concerns (in particular, leverage of market power and market foreclosure) but they are understood to be to two different sales strategies.

Tying is explicitly mentioned in Art 102 of the TFEU as an abusive conduct. According to Art 102(d) abuse may in particular consist in “conclusion of contracts subject to acceptance by the other parties of supplementary obligations which, by their nature or according to commercial usage, have no connection with the subject of such contracts.” This describes the nature of tying, i.e. the practice of supplying something on the condition that the customer purchases something else from the supplier as well.Even though bundling is not explicitly mentioned in Art 102 of the TFEU it is an established notion in EU competition law. Tying has been discussed e.g. in the case Hilti:Hilti was a supplier of a nail gun protected by a patent. Hilti did not have any patent on the nails used in the nail gun and there were independent manufacturers who produced Hilti-compatible nails. According to the independent manufacturers Hilti employed several selling practices which required the customers who bought the Hilti nail gun to purchase also nails from Hilti and these selling practices excluded other manufacturers from the nail market. The ECJ ruled that Hilti infringed Art 102 of the TFEU (then Art 82) because the selling practices that tied the Hilti nail gun to the “Hilti nails” limited the entry of the independent manufacturers of Hilti-compatible nails into the market.

It is important to bear in mind that not every case where two or more products are sold together constitutes an abusive conduct under Art 102(d) of the TFEU. Tying and bundling are in fact common business practices and they are routinely engaged in by both dominant and non-dominant firms. 

For instance, selling shoes together with shoelaces or a car with tyres as one product can be regarded as a normal selling practice that merely serves the needs and preferences of the consumers. Furthermore, tying and bundling of two or more components into one product is a fundamental part of several economic activities and they can lead to substantial savings in production, distribution and transaction costs as well as to quality improvements.This can in turn be reflected in the prices for which the products are offered for sale and in the more attractive products made available for the consumers. Other justified reasons for tying and bundling products together may be e.g. ensuring the optimal production performance, maintaining the supplier´s reputation or ensuring safety of the product.However, it can be noted on the basis of case law that the ECJ and the Commission have not always accepted product safety as a proper justification for tying and bundling.

II. Tying

As already mentioned, tying refers to a sales strategy where distinctive products are offered for sale as a combination. According to the Commission, tying occurs when a dominant firm makes the sale of one product (the tying product) conditional upon the purchase of another distinct product (the tied product) from the dominant firm or someone designated by it. In such a case only the tied product could be bought separately by the customers.The tying effect deprives the customers of choice of alternative products and it can take place on technical or contractual basis.Thus contractual tying refers to situations where the customers who purchase the tying product undertake also to purchase the tied product (and not the alternatives offered by competitors). Respectively, technical tying refers to situations where the tying product is designed in such a way that it only works properly with the tied product (and not with the alternatives offered by competitors). In such cases the tied product is typically physically integrated in the tying product. Alternatively, the customers can be deprived of choice of alternative products in less direct ways. The dominant firm may e.g. impose selling conditions under which it refuses to acknowledge guarantees unless the customers use the firm´s components, consumables or services.

III. Bundling

Bundling refers to the way products are offered and priced by a dominant firm.

According to the Commission, bundling occurs on where a package of two or more goods is offered for sale.A distinction between two different types of bundling can be made: Pure bundling refers to cases, where only the bundle (i.e. products jointly) is available and not the products separately.

In such a case the products are only sold jointly in fixed proportions.

Mixed bundling on the other hand refers to cases where the products are available separately but they are offered for sale at a discount price if bought as a bundle (i.e. the price is lower than the aggregate price of the separate products). Therefore mixed bundling can also be described as multi-product rebatebecause the price of the separate products is higher than the bundled price.

Mixed bundling (sometimes referred also to as commercial tying) is an indirect measure to achieve the same result as through contractual tying by inducing the customers to purchase the tied product through granting bonuses, rebates, discounts or other commercial advantage for such a purchase.

However, as the Commission has pointed out, the distinction between mixed bundling and pure bundling is not necessarily clear-cut because mixed bundling may come close to pure bundling if the prices charged for the individual offerings are high.

 

B. Underlying economic principles

The economic literature is ambiguous regarding the effects of tying and bundling. One of the main characteristics of a monopoly is the ability of one firm to raise prices above marginal cost level. Economic literature is questioning whether effects of tying and bundling can be transferred to other markets or not.

Tying and bundling have positive and negative effects.

Both strategies include the transfer of market power from a market with dominant position to secondary market where a company does not hold a dominant position. Given two markets, market A is a monopolistic market for one product – market B is a competitive market for a complementary product. The monopolistic company bundles its product from market A with a product of market B. Resulting negative effects of this strategy are:

  • competition constraints;

  • the reduction of demand for other goods supplied by competitors and

  • possible market foreclosure.

But also positive effects like efficiency gains due to reduction or solving of information and transaction problems and increased supply of varied products are possible.From a competition point of view it has to be analyzed whether tying or bundling strategies for certain products may be used to leverage market power to another market and harm competition and maximize profits for monopolistic companies. In economic literature, there are two contrary argumentation lines.

Followers of Chicago School disagree with the possible results of the leverage effect (R.A. Posner: Antitrust Law: An Economic Perspective, 1976 et al.). Their main argument is that monopoly profits can only be realized in one market and monopoly power itself not transferred to another market. Overall profits will not exceed the overall monopolist profits of one market and, therefore, companies which tie and bundle products have no incentive to tie and bundle but for efficiency reasons.This argument of the Chicago School is based on strict assumptions (monopolist is able to capture the entire willingness to pay of consumers, goods are consumed in fixed proportions, perfect competition in secondary market) which are not applicable for most existing markets.On the other hand, followers of the more recent Industrial Organization Theory argue that leverage effects are possible and might – under certain conditions – even lead to market foreclosure. Whinston shows that in imperfect markets product bundling is useful, if the monopolistic company fails a perfect price discrimination of the consumers in the monopolistic market. The monopolistic company may transfer its market power from the monopolistic market to the secondary competitive market of the bundled product and raise prices. As Whinston points out, the company is able to raise its overall profits at the cost of a decreased overall welfare and to squeeze competitors via an aggressive pricing strategy out of the secondary market.Bundling deters potential competitors from entering the market because potential competitors would have to enter the monopolistic market first and afterwards the competitive secondary market as well. As a result, bundling might lead to a market foreclosure and high barriers to entry. 

 

Modern economic literature rejects a per se legality or illegality approach of certain bundling or tying strategies. Instead a rule of reason approach with balancing of positive efficiency effects and negative anticompetitive effects is favoured.

C. Legal conditions and parameters

For tying and bundling to be considered abusive, from the case-law, the Discussion Paper

and the Commission’s Guidance we can conclude that for tying or bundling to be abusive, the following conditions must be fulfilled:

  1. the tying and tied products are distinct products;

  2. the tying practice is likely to lead to anti-competitive foreclosure;

  3. there is no objective justification for the tying or bundling.

In its Microsoft decision, the Commission also added lack of customer choice/coercion as a condition.

This can arise from the unavailability of the products separately, from pressure exerted on the customers through the promise of favorable treatment, or from pricing incentives which may be so powerful as to convince any customer to buy the bundle instead of separate products.

However, in the Commission’s guidance released after the Microsoft case well as in previous case-law, no mention of such a requirement is ever made. Logically, such coercion or lack of choice may be seen instrumental in the foreclosure effect that tying and/or bundling create.

I. Dominance

The first condition for exclusionary effects to arise requires dominance in the tying market. It is not necessary that the company also is dominant in the tied market. However, dominance also in the tied market renders the finding of an abuse more likely. In order to assess this properly it is normally necessary to define the relevant market(s) on which both the tying and the tied product are sold.

 













  • Keine Stichwörter